Government Intervention in Markets (Edexcel A Level Economics A)
Revision Note
Written by: Steve Vorster
Reviewed by: Jenna Quinn
Government Intervention in Markets
Nearly every economy in the world is a mixed economy and has varying degrees of government intervention
Government intervention is necessary for several reasons
Correct market failure: in many markets there is a less than optimal allocation of resources from society's point of view
In maximising their self-interest, firms and individuals will not self-correct this allocation of resources and there is a role for the government
They often achieve this by influencing the level of production or consumption
Earn government revenue: governments need money to provide essential services, public and merit goods
Revenue is raised through intervention such as taxation, privatisation, sale of licenses (e.g. 5G licenses), and sale of goods/services
Promote equity: to reduce the opportunity gap between the rich and poor
Support firms: in a global economy, governments choose to support key industries so as to help them remain competitive
Support poorer households: poverty has multiple impacts on both the individual and the economy
Intervention seeks to redistribute income (tax the rich and give to the poor) so as to reduce the impact of poverty
Four of the most common methods used to intervene in markets are indirect taxation, use of subsidies, maximum prices, and minimum prices
Indirect taxation
An indirect tax can be either ad valorem or specific
Ad Valorem tax
Value added tax (VAT) is 20% in the UK in 2024. The more goods/services consumed, the larger the tax bill
This causes the second shifted supply curve to diverge from the original supply curve
VAT raises significant government revenue. It is the third biggest source of tax revenue after income tax and national insurance in the UK
Diagram analysis
Initial equilibrium is at P1Q1
Supply shifts left due to the tax from S → S + tax
The two supply curves diverge as percentage tax means more tax per unit is paid at higher prices
Consumer incidence of tax is (P2 - P1) x Q2 - Area A
Producer incidence of tax is (P1 - P3) x Q2 - Area B
New equilibrium is at P2Q2
Final price is higher (P2) and QD is lower (Q2)
Specific tax on negative externality of production
Governments frequently tax firms that pollute or create harmful external costs in production
Diagram analysis
The free-market equilibrium is at PeQe - where MSB = MPC
Market failure exists as MSC > MSB at equilibrium
Optimum level of output is at Qopt
There is over-provision of this product
A specific tax shifts the supply curve left from S → S1
The tax does not completely eradicate the welfare loss but moves the market closer to the optimum level of output (Qopt)
The welfare loss has been reduced as shown in the diagram
The new market equilibrium is at P1Q1
This is a higher price and less output
There is less over-provision and so less market failure
The external costs have been reduced
Governments frequently tax the production of goods and services that create environmental harm or damaging health consequences. Some examples include intensive factory farming, oil drilling, the manufacture of chemicals and the construction of new roads or runways at airports
Subsidies
Governments frequently use subsidies to encourage production/consumption of merit goods such as energy efficient products, electric vehicles, healthcare, and education
Diagram analysis
The free-market equilibrium is at PeQe - where MPB = MSC
Market failure exists as MSB > MSC at equilibrium
Optimum level of output is at Qopt
There is under-consumption of this product
A subsidy shifts the supply curve right from S → S1
It does not completely eradicate the potential welfare gain but moves the market closer to the optimum level of output (Qopt)
The potential welfare gain has been reduced as shown in the diagram
The new market equilibrium is at P1Q1
This is a lower price and higher output
There is less under-consumption and so less market failure
Some of the external benefits available have been realised
Maximum Prices
Governments will often use maximum prices or price caps in order to help consumers. Sometimes they are used for long periods of time, e.g. housing rental markets. Other times they are short-term solutions to unusual price increases, e.g. fuel
A maximum price is set by the government below the existing free market equilibrium price and sellers cannot legally sell the good/service at a higher price
Diagram analysis
Initial market equilibrium is at PeQe
A maximum price is imposed at Pmax
The lower price reduces the incentive to supply and there is contraction in QS from Qe → Qs
The lower price increases the incentive to consume and there is an extension in QD from Qe → Qd
This creates a condition of excess demand QsQd
Some consumers benefit as they purchase at lower prices
Others are unable to purchase due to the shortage
This unmet demand usually encourages the creation of illegal markets (black/grey markets)
Minimum Prices
Governments will often use minimum prices in order to help producers or to decrease consumption of a demerit good e.g. alcohol
A minimum price is set by the government above the existing free market equilibrium price and sellers cannot legally sell the good/service at a lower price
Minimum prices are also used in the labour market to protect workers from wage exploitation. These are called minimum wages
Diagram analysis
Initial market equilibrium is at PeQe
A minimum price is imposed at Pmin
The higher price increases the incentive to supply and there is an extension in QS from Qe → Qs
The higher price decreases the incentive to consume and there is a contraction in QD from Qe → Qd
This creates a condition of excess supply QdQs
Differences in government responses to the excess supply
In agricultural markets, if a minimum price is set by the government producers benefit as they receive a higher price
Governments will often purchase the excess supply and export it
In demerit markets, producers suffer as QD contracts
Governments will not purchase the excess supply
Producers usually lower their output in the market to match the QD at the minimum price
Other Methods of Government Intervention
Trade Pollution Permits
Governments create a pollution permit market and issue permits to polluting firms
This helps to reduce negative externalities of production
Each permit is typically valid for the emission of one ton of pollutant
More polluting firms have to buy additional permits from less polluting firms
The price of the permit represents an additional cost of production
If the price of additional permits is more than the cost of investing in new pollution technology, firms will be incentivised to switch to cleaner technology:
Firms can then sell their spare permits and gain additional revenue
State Provision of Public Goods
Public goods are beneficial for society and are not provided by private firms due to the free rider problem
They are usually provided free at the point of consumption, but are paid for through general taxation
Examples include roads, parks, lighthouses, national defence
Provision of Information
Information gaps cause market failure
Governments can set up information portals so as to reduce the asymmetric information
Examples include job centres, consumer rights websites, nutritional labels like the traffic light system
Regulation
Governments create rules to limit harm from negative externalities of consumption/production
They create regulatory agencies to monitor that the rules are not broken
There are more than 90 regulators in the UK
Individuals or firms may be fined/imprisoned for breaking the rules
Examples of some industry regulators include the Environment Agency, Ofsted, and the Financial Conduct Authority
Last updated:
You've read 0 of your 5 free revision notes this week
Sign up now. It’s free!
Did this page help you?